Historical institutionalism

Historical institutionalism (HI) is a new institutionalist social science approach[1] that emphasizes how timing, sequences and path dependence affect institutions, and shape social, political, economic behavior and change.[2][3] Unlike functionalist theories and some rational choice approaches, historical institutionalism tends to emphasize that many outcomes are possible, small events and flukes can have large consequences, actions are hard to reverse once they take place, and that outcomes may be inefficient. A critical juncture may set in motion events that are hard to reverse, because of issues related to path dependency.[4][5][6][7] Historical institutionalists tend to focus on history (longer temporal horizons) to understand why specific events happen.[8]

The term "Historical Institutionalism" began appearing in publications in the early 1990s, although it had been used in the late 1980s.[9] The most widely cited historical institutionalist scholars are Peter Hall, Paul Pierson, Theda Skocpol, Douglass North, and Kathleen Thelen.[10] Prominent works of historical institutionalist scholarship have used both sociological and rationalist methods.[11][5][12] Due to a focus on events involving causal complexity (equifinality, complex interaction effects and path dependency),[13][14] historical institutionalist works tend to employ detailed comparative case studies.[15]

Old and new institutionalism

Kathleen Thelen and Sven Steinmo contrast New Institutionalism with "Old Institutionalism", which was overwhelmingly focused on detailed narratives of institutions, with little focus on comparative analyses. Thus, the Old Institutionalism was unhelpful for comparative research and explanatory theory. This "Old Institutionalism" began to be undermined when scholars increasingly highlighted how the formal rules and administrative structures of institutions were not accurately describing the behavior of actors and policy outcomes.[16]

Works, such as Karl Polanyi's The Great Transformation, Theda Skocpol's States and Social Revolutions, Philippe Schmitter's Still a Century of Corporatism?, Barrington Moore's Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, and Evans, Ruschemeyer and Skocpol's Bringing the State Back In have been characterized as precursors to Historical Institutionalism,[8][17][18][19] spawning a new research program.

Historical institutionalism is a predominant approach in research on the welfare state.[20][21] In the field of International Relations, John Ikenberry's After Victory and Abraham Newman's Protectors of Privacy are prominent works of historical institutionalist scholarship.[17]

The treatment of history

Unlike most western scholars who preceded them, including classical liberals, classical Marxists, empiricists, dialectical thinkers and positivists, historical institutionalists do not accept that history necessarily develops in a straightforward, linear fashion. Instead, they examine the conditions under which a particular trajectory was followed and not others, a phenomenon that Gabriel Almond refers to as the "historical cure".[22] As a consequence, specifying why particular paths were not taken is as important as specifying the actual trajectory of history.

As opposed to the old institutionalists, they postulate that history will not necessarily lead to a "happy" outcome (i.e. "fascism or democracy as the end of history").

Historical institutionalist works tend to reject functionalist accounts of institutions.[7][23] Therefore, they are suspicious of explanations for the emergence of institutions that work backwards from the functions of institutions to their origins.[23] Historical institutionalists tend to see origins behind the creation of institutions as the result of conflict and contestation, which then gets locked in and persists, even if the circumstances that resulted in the institution change.[7]

Mechanisms of institutional stability

The concept of path dependence is essential to historical institutionalist analyses.[24][25][26][27] Due to path dependence, institutions may have considerable stability and "stickiness", even in situations when the institutional leads to suboptimal arrangements. For Paul Pierson, path dependence entails that “outcomes at a ‘critical juncture’ trigger feedback mechanisms [negative or positive] that reinforce the recurrence of a particular pattern into the future.” Thus, path dependence makes it harder to reverse once a certain path has been taken, because there are increased costs to switching from the path. These paths may lead to outcomes are inefficient, but nonetheless persist, because of the costs involved in making substantial overhauls. An example of this is the QWERTY keyboard layout, which was efficient for typewriters to prevent jams in the 19th century and was implemented in computer keyboards in the 20th century. However, the QWERTY keyboard is arguably not as efficient as a computer keyboard could be, but the keyboard layout has persisted over time due to the costs involved in overhauling computer keyboards.[4] Jacob Hacker and Paul Pierson argue that other approaches to institutions may fall guilty of treating politics as if it were the film Groundhog Day where each day the participants just start over; in reality, past politics and policy legacies shape the interests, incentives, power and organizational abilities of political actors.[28]

According to Paul Pierson, the following factors contribute to institutional stability:[29]

  • Large setup costs: actors may stick with existing institutions because there are large setup costs associated with creating new ones
  • Learning effects: actors may stick with existing institutions because it is costly to learn about procedures and processes in new institutions
  • Coordination effects: actors may stick with existing institutions because it is too complex to coordinate multiple actors into creating new institutions
  • Adaptive expectations: actors may expend resources on an institution over another because it is likely to stay or become the dominant institution

These factors entail that actors have devoted resources into developing certain institution-specific skills and are unlikely to expend resources on alternative institutions.[30]

A related crux of historical institutionalism is that temporal sequences matter: outcomes depend upon the timing of exogenous factors (such as inter-state competition or economic crisis) in relation to particular institutional configurations (such as the level of bureaucratic professionalism or degree of state autonomy from class forces). For example, Theda Skocpol suggests that the democratic outcome of the English Civil War was a result of the fact that the comparatively weak English Crown lacked the military capacity to fight the landed upper-class. In contrast, the rise of rapid industrialization and fascism in Prussia when faced with international security threats was because the Prussian state was a “highly bureaucratic and centralized agrarian state” composed by “men closely ties to landed notables”.[31] Thomas Ertman, in his account of state building in medieval and early modern Europe, argues that variations in the type of regime built in Europe during this period can be traced to one macro-international factor and two historical institutional factors. At the macro-structural level, the “timing of the onset of sustained geopolitical competition” created an atmosphere of insecurity that appeared best addressed by consolidating state power. The timing of the onset of competition is critical for Ertman's explanation. States that faced competitive pressures early had to consolidate through patrimonial structures, since the development of modern bureaucratic techniques had not yet arrived. States faced with competitive pressures later on the other hand, could take advantage of advancements in training and knowledge to promote a more technically oriented civil service.[32][33]

An important element to historical institutionalism is that it may cement certain distributions of power or increase asymmetries of power through policy feedbacks, "lock in" effects and stickiness.[2] For example, France has a permanent seat on the UN Security Council because of its power and status at the end of World War II, yet it would likely not get a permanent seat if the UN Security Council were re-designed decades later.[2]

Mechanisms of institutional change

Historical institutionalists have identified major shocks, such as wars and revolutions, as important factors that lead to institutional change because those shocks create "critical junctures" whereby certain path dependencies get created. One prominent account in this vein is John Ikenberry's work on international orders which argues that after major wars, the dominant powers set up world orders that are favorable to their interests.[34]

Aside from shocks, historical institutionalists have also identified numerous factors that subtly lead to institutional change.[35] These include:

  • Layering: grafting new rules onto old rules[36][37][38][39][40]
  • Displacement: when relevant actors leave existing institutions and go to new or alternative institutions[36][37]
  • Conversion: old rules are reinterpreted and redirected to apply to new goals, functions and purposes[36][37][41][40]
  • Drift: old rules fail to apply to situations that they were intended for because of changing social conditions[36][37][42][43]
  • Exhaustion: an institution overextends itself to the point that it does not have the capacity to fulfill its purposes and ultimately breaks down[37][44]

As part of these subtle changes, there may be widespread noncompliance with the formal rules of an institution, prompting change.[35] There may also be shifts in the balance of power between the social coalitions that comprise the institution.[35][45]

Reception

Historical institutionalism is not a unified intellectual enterprise (see also new institutionalism). Some scholars are oriented towards treating history as the outcome of rational and purposeful behavior based on the idea of equilibrium (see rational choice). They rely heavily on quantitative approaches and formal theory. Others, more qualitative oriented scholars, reject the idea of rationality and instead emphasize the idea that randomness and accidents matter in political and social outcomes.[5] There are unsolvable epistemological differences between both approaches.[46] However given the historicity of both approaches, and given their focus on institutions, both can fall under "historical institutionalism".

Munck argues that work that emphasizes critical junctures as causes has two problems: (i) the problem of infinite regress (the notion that the cause of events can constantly be pushed back further in time), and (ii) the problem of distal non-recurring causes (convincingly arguing that a distant non-recurring event caused a much later event).[47]

Avner Greif and David Laitin have criticized the notion of increased returns.[48]

Sociological institutionalists and ideational scholars have criticized versions of Historical Institutionalism that adopt materialist and rationalist ontologies.[10] Scholars who use ideational approaches argue that institutional change occurs during episodes when institutions are perceived be failing (such as during economic crises) or during episodes of uncertainty, as this creates room for an exchange of ideas and a receptivity for institutional change.[10][49][50][51] Political scientists such as Henry Farrell, Martha Finnemore, Mark Blyth, Oddny Helgadóttir, and William Kring argue that Historical Institutionalism has over time tended to engage more with rational choice institutionalism than with sociological institutionalism.[18][10] Vincent Pouliot similarly writes that "soft rational choice... informs most versions of [Historical Institutionalism]."[38] According to Michael Zurn, Historical institutionalism "lacks a theory of action."[52]

In Paradigms and Sand Castles, an influential book on research design in comparative politics, Barbara Geddes argues that there are methodological limits to the kind of path-dependent arguments that is often found in Historical Institutionalist research.[53] She argues that it is hard to rule out rival explanations for a proposed outcome and to precisely identify one purported critical juncture or another.[53]

Major institutionalist scholars and books

See also

References

  1. Steinmo, Sven (2008). "Historical institutionalism". In Della Porta, Donatella; Keating, Michael (eds.). Approaches and Methodologies in the Social Sciences. pp. 118–138. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511801938.008. ISBN 9780511801938. Retrieved 2020-03-05. {{cite book}}: |website= ignored (help)
  2. Voeten, Erik (2019). "Making Sense of the Design of International Institutions". Annual Review of Political Science. 22 (1): 147–163. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-041916-021108. ISSN 1094-2939.
  3. Farrell, Henry; Newman, Abraham L. (2010). "Making global markets: Historical institutionalism in international political economy". Review of International Political Economy. 17 (4): 609–638. doi:10.1080/09692291003723672. ISSN 0969-2290. S2CID 153647117.
  4. Pierson, Paul (2000). "Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics". American Political Science Review. 94 (2): 251–267. doi:10.2307/2586011. hdl:1814/23648. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 2586011. S2CID 154860619.
  5. Steinmo, S; Thelen, K; Longstreth, F, eds. (1992), Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, New York: Cambridge University Press.
  6. Capoccia, Giovanni; Kelemen, R. Daniel (2007). "The Study of Critical Junctures: Theory, Narrative, and Counterfactuals in Historical Institutionalism". World Politics. 59 (3): 341–369. doi:10.1017/S0043887100020852. ISSN 1086-3338.
  7. Thelen, Kathleen; Conran, James (2016). Fioretos, Orfeo; Falleti, Tulia G.; Sheingate, Adam (eds.). Institutional Change. Vol. 1. Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199662814.013.3. ISBN 978-0-19-966281-4.
  8. Katznelson, Ira (2007). Preferences and Situations : Points of Intersection Between Historical and Rational Choice In. Russell Sage Foundation. pp. 1–26. ISBN 978-1-61044-333-3. OCLC 945610829.
  9. Mahoney, James (2017). "Shift Happens: The Historical Institutionalism of Kathleen Thelen". PS: Political Science & Politics. 50 (4): 1115–1119. doi:10.1017/S1049096517001494. ISSN 1049-0965.
  10. Blyth, Mark; Helgadottir, Oddny; Kring, William (2016-05-02). Fioretos, Orfeo; Falleti, Tulia G; Sheingate, Adam (eds.). "Ideas and Historical Institutionalism". Oxford Handbooks Online. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199662814.013.8.
  11. "Historical Institutionalism and International Relations". E-International Relations. 16 April 2012. Retrieved 2020-03-05.
  12. Hall, Peter A.; Taylor, Rosemary C. R. (1996). "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms". Political Studies. 44 (5): 936–957. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9248.1996.tb00343.x. hdl:11858/00-001M-0000-0012-59C1-5. ISSN 0032-3217. S2CID 3133316.
  13. George, Alexander L.; Bennett, Andrew (2005). Case Studies and Theory Development in the Social Sciences. MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-30307-1. OCLC 944521872.
  14. Gerring, John (2007). Case Study Research: Principles and Practices. Cambridge University Press. pp. 61–62. ISBN 978-0-521-85928-8.
  15. Pierson, Paul (1993). "When Effect Becomes Cause: Policy Feedback and Political Change". World Politics. 45 (4): 595–628. doi:10.2307/2950710. ISSN 0043-8871. JSTOR 2950710. S2CID 154900007.
  16. "Structuring politics historical institutionalism comparative analysis". Cambridge University Press. 1992. pp. 3–4. Retrieved 2020-02-29.
  17. Fioretos, Orfeo (2011). "Historical Institutionalism in International Relations". International Organization. 65 (2): 367–399. doi:10.1017/S0020818311000002. ISSN 1531-5088. S2CID 145270225.
  18. Farrell, Henry; Finnemore, Martha (2016). Fioretos, Orfeo; Falleti, Tulia G.; Sheingate, Adam (eds.). Global Institutions without a Global State. Vol. 1. Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199662814.013.34. ISBN 978-0-19-966281-4.
  19. Béland, Daniel; Campbell, Andrea Louise; Weaver, R. Kent (2022). "Policy Feedback: How Policies Shape Politics". Cambridge University Press: 2. doi:10.1017/9781108938914. ISBN 9781108938914.
  20. Lynch, Julia; Rhodes, Martin (2016-05-02). Fioretos, Orfeo; Falleti, Tulia G.; Sheingate, Adam (eds.). Historical Institutionalism and the Welfare State. Vol. 1. Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199662814.013.25. ISBN 978-0-19-966281-4.
  21. Katznelson, Ira (1998). "The Doleful Dance of Politics and Policy: Can Historical Institutionalism Make a Difference?". American Political Science Review. 92 (1): 191–197. doi:10.2307/2585938. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 2585938. S2CID 147672846.
  22. Almond, Gabriel (1956), "Comparative Political Systems", Journal of Politics, 18 (3): 391–409, doi:10.2307/2127255, JSTOR 2127255, S2CID 145761427.
  23. Thelen, Kathleen (2004). How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan. Cambridge University Press. p. 25. ISBN 978-0-521-54674-4.
  24. Irving, Lichbach Mark; Zuckerman, Alan S. (1997-08-28). Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-58668-9.
  25. Mahoney, James; Schensul, Daniel (2006-03-16). "Historical Context and Path Dependence". Oxford Handbooks Online: 454–471. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199270439.003.0024. ISBN 0199270430.
  26. Mahoney, James (2000). "Path Dependence in Historical Sociology". Theory and Society. 29 (4): 507–548. doi:10.1023/A:1007113830879. ISSN 0304-2421. JSTOR 3108585. S2CID 145564738.
  27. Christiansen, Thomas; Verdun, Amy (2020). "Historical Institutionalism in the Study of European Integration". Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics. doi:10.1093/acrefore/9780190228637.013.178. ISBN 978-0-19-022863-7.
  28. Hacker, Jacob S.; Pierson, Paul (2014). "After the "Master Theory": Downs, Schattschneider, and the Rebirth of Policy-Focused Analysis". Perspectives on Politics. 12 (3): 643–662. doi:10.1017/s1537592714001637. ISSN 1537-5927. S2CID 154841537.
  29. Pierson, Paul (2000). "The Limits of Design: Explaining Institutional Origins and Change". Governance. 13 (4): 475–499. doi:10.1111/0952-1895.00142. ISSN 0952-1895.
  30. Pierson, Paul (2004). Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-11715-7.
  31. Skocpol, Theda (1973), "A Critical Review of Barrington Moore's Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy", Politics and Society, 4 (1): 1–34, doi:10.1177/003232927300400101, S2CID 143910152.
  32. Thomas, Ertman (1997), Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  33. Whitehead, Richard (2002, October). “In Debate: The Casual Focus of Historical Institutionalism”. Paper presented at Temple University course seminar on Authoritarian Regimes, Philadelphia, PA.
  34. Ikenberry, G. John (2001). After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order After Major Wars, New Edition. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-16921-7.
  35. Capoccia, Giovanni (2016). "When Do Institutions "Bite"? Historical Institutionalism and the Politics of Institutional Change". Comparative Political Studies. 49 (8): 1095–1127. doi:10.1177/0010414015626449. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 146602221.
  36. Mahoney, James; Thelen, Kathleen, eds. (2009), "A Theory of Gradual Institutional Change", Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, Cambridge University Press, pp. 15–18, doi:10.1017/cbo9780511806414.003, ISBN 978-0-521-11883-5
  37. Streeck, Wolfgang; Thelen, Kathleen Ann (2005). Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. Oxford University Press. pp. 19–31. ISBN 978-0-19-928046-9.
  38. Pouliot, Vincent (2020). "Historical Institutionalism Meets Practice Theory: Renewing the Selection Process of the United Nations Secretary-General". International Organization. 74 (4): 742–772. doi:10.1017/S002081832000020X. ISSN 0020-8183. S2CID 225798719.
  39. Schickler, Eric (2001). Disjointed Pluralism: Institutional Innovation and the Development of the U.S. Congress. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-04926-7. JSTOR j.ctt7rr34.
  40. Thelen, Kathleen (2004). How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-54674-4.
  41. Bleich, Erik (2018). "Historical Institutionalism and Judicial Decision-Making: Ideas, Institutions, and Actors in French High Court Hate Speech Rulings". World Politics. 70 (1): 53–85. doi:10.1017/S0043887117000272. ISSN 0043-8871. S2CID 158916987.
  42. Hacker, Jacob S. (2004). "Privatizing Risk without Privatizing the Welfare State: The Hidden Politics of Social Policy Retrenchment in the United States". The American Political Science Review. 98 (2): 243–260. doi:10.1017/S0003055404001121. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 4145310. S2CID 14798241.
  43. Thelen, Kathleen (2004). How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-54674-4.
  44. Streeck, Wolfgang (2010). Re-Forming Capitalism: Institutional Change in the German Political Economy. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-161445-3.
  45. Mahoney, James; Thelen, Kathleen, eds. (2009), "A Theory of Gradual Institutional Change", Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, Cambridge University Press, pp. 8–10, doi:10.1017/cbo9780511806414.003, ISBN 978-0-521-11883-5
  46. Bates, Robert; et al., Analytic Narratives, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  47. Munck, Gerardo L. (2022). "The Theoretical Foundations of Critical Juncture Research: Critique and Reconstruction". Critical Junctures and Historical Legacies. Rowman and Littlefield. SSRN 3889801.
  48. Greif, Avner; Laitin, David D. (2004). "A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change". American Political Science Review. 98 (4): 633–652. doi:10.1017/s0003055404041395. ISSN 0003-0554. S2CID 1983672.
  49. Farrell, Henry; Quiggin, John (2017-06-01). "Consensus, Dissensus, and Economic Ideas: Economic Crisis and the Rise and Fall of Keynesianism". International Studies Quarterly. 61 (2): 269–283. doi:10.1093/isq/sqx010. ISSN 0020-8833.
  50. Hall, Peter A. (1993). "Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain". Comparative Politics. 25 (3): 275–296. doi:10.2307/422246. ISSN 0010-4159. JSTOR 422246.
  51. Blyth, Mark (2013). "Paradigms and Paradox: The Politics of Economic Ideas in Two Moments of Crisis". Governance. 26 (2): 197–215. doi:10.1111/gove.12010. ISSN 1468-0491.
  52. Zürn, Michael (2016), Rixen, Thomas; Viola, Lora Anne; Zürn, Michael (eds.), "Historical Institutionalism and International Relations—Strange Bedfellows?", Historical Institutionalism and International Relations, Oxford University Press, pp. 199–228, doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198779629.003.0008, ISBN 978-0-19-877962-9
  53. Geddes, Barbara (2003). Paradigms and Sand Castles: Theory Building and Research Design in Comparative Politics. University of Michigan Press. pp. 140–141. doi:10.3998/mpub.11910. ISBN 978-0-472-09835-4. JSTOR 10.3998/mpub.11910.

Further reading

  • Daniel W. Drezner (2010) "Is historical institutionalism bunk?" Review of International Political Economy, 17:4, 791-804
  • Peter A. Hall, “Historical Institutionalism in Rationalist and Sociological Perspective,” in James Mahoney and Kathleen Thelen, Explaining Institutional Change (Cambridge University Press 2010).
  • Pierson, Paul. 2000. "Path Dependence, Increasing Returns, and the Study of Politics." American Political Science Review 33, 6/7:251-67.
  • Fioretos, Orfeo (ed.). International Politics and Institutions in Time. Oxford University Press.
  • Fioretos, O. (2011). "Historical Institutionalism in International Relations." International Organization, 65(2), 367–399.
  • Fioretos, Orfeo, Tulia G. Falleti, and Adam Sheingate. 2016. The Oxford Handbook of Historical Institutionalism. Oxford University Press.
  • Steinmo, Sven. 2008. "Historical Institutionalism." in Approaches and Methodologies in the Social Sciences. Cambridge University Press.
  • Thelen, Kathleen. 2002. "How Institutions Evolve: Insights from Comparative-Historical Analysis." in Mahoney, James and Dueschemeyer, Dietrich, eds. Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences. Cambridge University Press.
  • Peter Hall and David Soskice. Varieties of Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 2000.
  • Kathleen Thelen, “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.” Annual Review of Political Science 1999: 369–404.
  • Kathleen Thelen. "Varieties of Capitalism: Trajectories of Liberalization and the New Politics of Social Solidarity." Annual Review of Political Science. 2012; 15:137- 159.
  • Henry Farrell and Abraham Newman. Domestic Institutions Beyond the Nation State: Charting the New Interdependence Approach. 2014. World Politics 66, 2:331- 363.
  • Henry Farrell and Abraham L. Newman (2010) "Making global markets: Historical institutionalism in international political economy." Review of International Political Economy, 17:4, 609-638
  • Rixen, Thomas, Lora Anne Viola, Michael Zürn (eds.). 2016. Historical Institutionalism and International Relations: Explaining Institutional Development in World Politics.[1] Oxford University Press.
  • Waylen, G. (2009). What Can Historical Institutionalism Offer Feminist Institutionalists? Politics & Gender, 5(2), 245–253.
  1. Historical Institutionalism and International Relations: Explaining Institutional Development in World Politics. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press. 2016-08-09. ISBN 978-0-19-877962-9.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.